The most comprehensive study of the costs related to visual impairment to date was produced in Australia by Taylor et al.
1,16 Costs were classified into the categories listed in
Table 3, which shows the costs included in the Australian study
1 and two others with which it will be contrasted. The categories include direct health care costs, indirect costs, and the costs associated with the loss of well-being. Direct health care costs can be further divided into hospital (both inpatient and outpatient) and other health costs (pharmaceuticals, imaging, pathology, optometry, aged care, other health professionals, and other medical expense). For this discussion, we have relabeled the costs because the term “indirect costs” has been used in different studies to refer to overhead, productivity loss, or any cost not directly related to the monetary costs of medical care. The relabeled terms include monetary expenditures on health care (medical and other), monetary expenditures on things other than health care (mainly aids and adaptations such as Braille devices and stair lighting, but also potential travel costs and other monetary expenditures), loss of family member productivity, deadweight losses, loss of patient productivity, and loss of patient well-being. We have placed these alternative labels in parentheses beside the item labels in
Table 3. The simplest way to clarify costs in a study is to provide a comprehensive list in a manuscript that allows both the peer-reviewers and the readers of the published manuscript to regroup if necessary.
The Australian study's authors identified the limitation that health expenditure data included all eye disease, rather than only visually impairing conditions. However, this limitation is a minor one, as the proportion of non–visually impairing eye conditions included in the study was small.
Individual's and family members' expenditures for aids and other modifications are part of the non–health-care monetary costs. All costs related to the condition but not paid to someone in the health care system are in this category. For example, spectacles or intraocular lenses would be “other” health costs, whereas canes or guide dogs would probably be in this non–health-care category. Notably, different aspects of cost are “medicalized” in different countries; in some places families provide most of the care, whereas in others, formal health care is more common.
In addition to the monetary costs, the Australian study accounted for the value of the time that informal carergivers spend in providing care.
1,16 Taylor et al.
1 used a small, detailed study of individual patients' experiences to calculate the value of caregivers' time. They also accounted for the loss of income and loss of well-being among those who were blind. Loss of income was based exclusively on the lower employment rate attributable to visual impairment. They did not include lower wages, reduced hours worked, or impediments to promotion; such data are available in the United States.
3 The authors also included the time lost from future work as a result of premature mortality attributable to vision loss. They calculated the present value by using a 1.55% real discount rate, to express the value of future productivity loss as if the entire flow of productivity were available today. The 1.55% discount rate places a relatively high value on the future, incorporating an expectation of increased productivity. They also include a measure of the loss of well-being, monetizing the value of DALYs by using a 3.3% discount rate and assuming a value of a statistical life year of A$162,561. They appropriately included only the economic inefficiency cost due to changes in behavior related to the taxes to support transfers.
17
The discount rate deserves further discussion. Discounting formalizes the comparison of the value of costs and benefits today with those in future years. Suggested standard discount rates range from as low as 0% to as high as 6%.
9 Future costs will be valued at only half their present value in 12 years if the discount rate is 6% and in 24 years if the discount rate is 3%. Thus, the rate chosen has important implications for the value of future outcomes. Some recommendations suggest a single discount rate for logical and mathematically pragmatic reasons.
8 This notion contrasts with the Australian study, in which the discount rate was tailored to the nature of the stream being discounted.
1,16 Differential discount rates are acceptable as long as researchers transparently state the rates and justify the choices.